EVOLUTION OF THE INDIAN ECONOMY

 

Background


The economic profile of India was in complete distress at the time of independence. Being a typical case of colonial economy, India was serving a purpose of development not for herself but a foreign land-the United Kingdom. Both agriculture and industry were having structural distortions while the state was playing not even a marginal role

There was not only the unilateral transfer of investible capital to Britain by the colonial state (the 'drain of wealth'), but the unequal exchange was day by day crippling India's commerce, trade and the thriving handloom industry, too. The colonial state practiced policies which were great impediments in the process of development in the country. Throughout the colonial rule, the economic vision that the state had was to increase India's capacity to export primary products, and increase the purchase/import of the British manufactured goods and raise revenues to meet the drain of capital as well as meet the revenue requirements of the imperial defence.

At the time of Independence,its literacy was only 17 per cent with 32.5 years of life expectancy at birth

Industrialisation oflndia was also neglected by the colonisers-the infrastructure was not built to industrialise India but to exploit its raw materials. Indian capitalists who did emerge were highly dependent on British commercial capital and many sectors of the industry were dominated by British firms, e.g., shipping, banking, insurance, coal, plantation crops and jute.

The pre-independence period was altogether a period of near stagnation showing almost no change in the structure of production or in the levels of productivity-the aggregate real output during the first half of the 20th century estimated at less than 2 per cent a year or less

The overall economic performance of India under the British rule was very low. According to economic statistian Angus Maddison, there was no per capita growth in India from 1600 to 1870-per capita growth was a meagre 0.2 per cent from 1870 to 1947, compared with 1 per cent in the UK.

PRIME MOVING FORCE— AGRICULTURE VS. INDUSTRY


A topical issue of debate regarding India has been the choice for the sector which will lead the process of development. The government of the time opted for industry to be India’s prime moving force of the economy. Whether India should have gone for agriculture as its prime moving force for better prospects of development, is a highly debatable issue even today among experts.

Every economy has to go for its development through exploitation of its natural and human resources. There are priorities of objectives set by the economy which is attempted to be realised in a proper time frame. The availability and the non-availability of resources (natural as well as human) are not the only issues which make an economy decide to declare whether it opts for agriculture or industry as its prime moving force. There are many more socio-political compulsions and objectives which play their roles in such decision making.

The political leadership selected industry as the leading force of the economy after independence— this was already decided by the dominant group of the nationalist leaders way back in the mid-1930s when they felt the need for economic planning in India before setting up the National Planning Committee (1938).

pre-requisites which India lacked to declare industry as its prime mover


(i) Almost no presence of infrastructure sector i.e. power, transportation and communication.

(ii) Negligible presence of the infrastructure industries i.e. iron and steel, cement, coal, crude oil, oil refining and electricity.

(iii) Lack of investible capital—be the case of either the government or the private sector.

(iv) Absence of the required technology to support the process of industrialisation and no research and development.

(v) Lack of skilled manpower.

(vi) Absence of entrepreneurship among the people.

(vii) Absence of the market for industrial goods.

(viii)Many other sociopsychological factors which were negative forces for the proper industrialisation of the economy.

Why India declared Agriculture as its prime mover


(i) The country was having the natural resource of fertile land which was fit for cultivation.

(ii) The human resource was not requiring any kind of higher training.

By only organising our land ownership, irrigation and other inputs to agriculture India could have gone for better prospects of development. Once there was no crises of food, shelter, basic healthcare, etc. to the masses, one goal of development could have been realised—a general welfare of the people. Once the masses were able to achieve a level of purchasing capacity, India could have gone for the expansion of industries. India was capable of generating as much surplus income for its masses as was required by the emerging industries for a market success. The People’s Republic of China did the same in 1949—taking a realistic evaluation of its resources, it declared agriculture as its prime moving force for the economy. The surplus generated out of agriculture was suitably invested to develop the pre-requisites for industrialisation and the country went for it in 1970s.

The emergence of industrial China was so vibrant that its impact was felt in the so-called highly developed and industrialised economies of the world—the industrial homework of China catapulted it into a giant.

Was the political leadership of independent India not able to analyse the realities as we did above and conclude that agriculture should have been the moving force of the economy in place of industry? Is it possible that Pandit Nehru in command could have missed the rational analysis of the Indian realities, a giant among the Asian visionaries of the time (Mao was still to emerge on the international scene)? How India could have not opted for agriculture as its prime moving force whose leadership had fought the nationalist movement on the Gandhian fervour of villages, agriculture and rural development. Even if Gandhi was not in the Government there were many devout Gandhians in it and no one should doubt that the main internal force which vibrated throughout the governmental decisions were nothing but ‘Gandhian Socialism’. There were many decisions which were taken under the influence of the main political force of the times, still some very vital ones were influenced by the visionary hunches of the political leadership mainly being J.L. Nehru. This is why the economic thinking of independent India is considered and said to be nurtured by the Nehruvian Economics still today. If we go through the major literatures on the Indian economic history, views of the critiques of the time and the contemporary experts, we may be able to feel the answer as to why India went for industry as its prime moving force in place of an obvious and logical choice of agriculture (we should not be happy to know that even today this is a highly debatable issue among experts):

(i) Looking at the resources available, agriculture would have been the obvious choice as the prime moving force (PMF) of the economy (i.e. cultivable land and the manpower). But as Indian agriculture was using the traditional tools and technology its modernisation as well as future mechanisation (latter to some extent) would have been blocked due to the lack of indigenous industrial support. If we had gone for import this would have required enough foreign reserves and a natural dependence on foreign countries. By choosing industry as the PMF we were going to industrialise the economy as well as modernise our traditional mode of farming.

(ii) The dominant ideology around the world as well as in the WB and the IMF was in favour of industrialisation as a means to faster growth which could be translated into faster development. These international bodies were supporting the member countries from every point of view to industrialise. Same was the case with the developed economies. It was possible not only to industrialise faster on these supports but a hope for emerging as an industrial exporter was also there. Such kind of supports were not being offered by them to an economy going to opt for agriculture as its PMF. Basically, going for the sector agriculture was considered a symbol of ‘backwardness’ at that time also. The political leadership wanted to carry India ahead, and not in the backward direction. It was only in the 1990s that the world and the WB/IMF changed its opinion regarding agriculture sector—and emphasis on this sector by an economy was no more considered a sign of backwardness.

(iii) The Second World War has proved the supremacy of defence power. For defence a country needs not only support of science and technology but an industrial base also. India also required a powerful defence base for herself as a deterrent force. By opting for industry as her PMF the economy tried to solve many challenges simultaneously—first, industry will give faster growth, second, agriculture will be modernised in time and third the economy will be able to develop its own defence force. Since the economy had opted for scientific and technological preparedness also, its achievements were to sustain the pace of modernising world out there (this seems taking place in India to a great extent.).

(iv) Even before independence, there was a socio-economic consensus among social scientists along with the nationalist leaders, that India needed a boost towards social change as the country lagged behind in the areas of modernisation. A break from the traditional and outmoded way of life and cultivation of a scientific outlook was a must for the country. Such feelings also made the political leadership of the time go in favour of wholehearted industrialisation.

(v) By the time India got her independence the might of industrialisation was already proven and there were no doubts regarding its efficacy.

Given above are some of the important reasons that worked to make Indian political leadership go in favour of opting industry as the economy’s prime moving force. Probably, the resource-related and temperamental realities of India got marginalised in hopes and wishes of a future industrialised and developed India. It is yet impossible to conclude whether the economy has completely failed to do so. Experts have divided opinions on this issue.

The last decade of the 20 th century (i.e. the decade of 1990s) saw major changes taking place in the world economic idea about the agriculture sector. It was no more a symbol of backwardness for an economy if it had started emphasising its agriculture sector as the engine of growth and development. China had proved to the world that how agriculture could be made the prime moving force of economy and generate internal as well as external strength to emerge as an industrial economy. In the wake of ongoing reform process India was introspecting almost all economic policies it followed since independence. It was time for agriculture sector to have the prime attention. A major shift took place in the Indian economic thinking when the Government announced in 2002 that now onwards, in place of industry, agriculture will be the prime moving force (PMF) of the economy. This was a policy shift of historic importance which was announced by the highest economic think tank of the country—the Planning Commission—as the economy commenced the Tenth Plan (2002–07)

three major challenges faced by the economy:


1. Economy will be able to achieve food security with the increase in the agricultural production. Besides, the agricultural surplus will generate exports in the globalising world economy benefiting out of the WTO regime.

2. The challenge of poverty alleviation will be solved to a great extent as the emphasis will make agriculture a higher income-generating occupation and induce growth in the rural economy by generating more gainful employment.

3. The situation of India as an example of ‘market failure’ will cease.

Though the world outlook towards agriculture sector had changed by the early 1990s, the Government of India announced the policy shift more than one decade later. There is now a consensus among the experts, policy-makers and the governments alike that for development to take place in India it is necessary to strengthen the sector on which the masses depend for their income and livelihood. More than 65 per cent of the Indian population depends on agriculture and allied activities while only 18.5 per cent of the gross domestic product (GDP) comes from the sector. It means that above 65 per cent of Indian population shares just 18.5 per cent of the gross income generated by the economy. The rest of the population that does not depend on agriculture (i.e. below 35 per cent) share 81.5 per cent gross income generated by the economy. The gap of income shows the lower purchasing power of the people involved in agricultural activities—which is more than two-third of the total population. How market can succeed in such a situation and what to ask of the market economy. As the economy was more in favour of market economy, the situation of market failure needed to be arrested The income of the population dependent on the agriculture sector needed strengthening. 

major policies which are intended towards the strengthening of the agriculture sector:


New Agriculture Policy, 2000
National Agricultural Insurance Scheme, 1999–00
Exim Policy, 2002–07
Second Green Revolution
Bharat Nirman

New Agriculture Policy, 2000


The policy mainly intends to convert agriculture into the category of industry so that the population dependent on it could earn income and profit out of agricultural activities with the same pace and mode as the industry has enabled the population dependent on the industrial activities.

National Agricultural Insurance Scheme, 1999–00


The new insurance scheme launched for agriculture intends to provide insurance coverage to all agricultural activities right from seeds, sowing, harvesting to marketing risks—a necessary support to which the industry had access but agriculture had no reach.

Exim Policy, 2002–07


The Export Import Policy, 2002–07 for the first time accepted at the policy level the long-standing opinion of the experts—that a one per cent increase of the agricultural products in India’s exports supplies additional Rs. 8,500 crores to the agricultural sector. Many policy initiatives were taken to increase the share of agriculture in the total export of the economy

Second Green Revolution


A major programme to boost the agricultural production with the sustainable approach was launched in 2004 with an initial corpus of Rs. 50,000 crore.

Bharat Nirman


A major programme to focus on the agricultural and rural infrastructure (totalling six items) was launched by the Government in 2005 with the ultimate intention of strengthening rural economy

Others


Similarly, many time-bound programmes and schemes have been launched since 2002 which focus on the agriculture sector and the rural areas from different angles— education, electricity, wage, as well as self-employment, healthcare, communication, etc

Looking at the size of population depending upon the agriculture sector, comparatively longer government apathy to the agricultural realities and the late start of reform process in it make things very tough to effect visible changes in the sector in a short time. It also requires comparatively longer period of time. We will then be able to see the visible results of the policy shift as well as the results of the economic reforms in the agriculture sector provided there remains a continued political commitment to the cause. One positive development of the last decade has been that India has been able to reach a silent political consensus on some of the very important aspects of development (for example—on the process of economic reforms, foreign investment, deregulation, social justice, emphasis on agricuture, priority to the social sector, etc.) which gives us hope that the economy will be able to take care of the agriculture sector in due course and more accelerated growth and development can be achieved

Planned and Mixed economy


Economic planning was the answer to the mass poverty and resource and income disparity in India. The Great depression of 1929 had proved the downside of capitalist economies. This was increased by the challenges faced in reconstruction after the Second World War. Besides, during the same time, the Soviet Union and such state economies were successful in promoting the success of the state economy. Thirdly, the idea of the state neutralising a market failure was dominant around the world.
Thus, state intervention was necessary.

Now that a capitalist economy was out of question, it was a choice between a state economy and a mixed economy. It was here that the then leaders showed thinking beyond the times. Although state economies were convincing enough, especially during the time, the importance of the private sector was recognised, and the state was decided to become a mixed economy.

Need for PSUs


(i) Infrastructural needs: Irrespective of whether an economy is agrarian or industrial, it needs infrastructure. This requires heavy investments, technology, skilled manpower, which were not feasible for private sector. Thus, it was only the government that could shoulder the responsibility.

(ii) Industrial needs: The basic industries like iron and steel, cement, coal, crude oil, etc. could not be managed by the existent private sector units.

(iii) Employment generation: There was immediacy for a social change in the country, to lift many a person out of poverty. Only PSUs could put jobs at government disposal, which could then be given depending on eligibility.

Emphasis on the Public Sector


The state was to be given an active and dominant role in the economy, it was very much decided by the time India became independent. There were no doubts about it in the minds of the people who formed the dominant political force at the time. Naturally, there was going to be a giant structure of the government-controlled enterprises to be known as the public sector undertakings (PSUs). Criticism aside, there were at that time, a strong logic behind the glorification of PSUs. Some of the reasons for heavy investments in the PSUs were purely natural while others were consequential in nature. There were certain highly commendable objectives set for them, some other goals would go on to serve the very soul of the mixed economy. We must go for an impartial and rational analysis of the matter, in the midst of all the criticism of PSUs and the contemporary moves of privatising them, to understand their roles in the Indian economy. We may understand the reasons behind the ambitious expansion of the PSUs in the face of the following major requirements.

Infrastructural Needs


Every economy whether it is agrarian, industrial or post-industrial, needs suitable levels of infrastructure such as-power, transportation and communication. Without their healthy presence and expansion, no economy can grow, and develop.
At the eve of Independence, India was having almost no presence of these three basic requirements. There was just a beginning in the area of railways, and post and telegraph. Power was restricted to selective homes of government and the princely states. [It means, even if India had opted for agriculture as its prime moving force (PMF), it had to develop the infrastructure sector.]
These sectors require too much capital investment as well as heavy enginering and technological support for their development. Expansion of the infrastructure sector was considered not possible by the private sector of the time as they could possibly not manage the following components:
(i) heavy investment (in domestic as well as foreign currencies),
(ii) technology,
(iii) skilled manpower, and
(iv) entrepreneurship
Even if these inputs were available to the private sector it was not feasible for them as there was no market for such infrastructure. These infrastructures were essential for the economy, but they needed either subsidised or almost free supply as the masses lacked the market-determined purchasing capacity. Under these typical condition, it was only the government which could have shouldered the responsibility. The government could have managed not only the inputs required for the development of the sector but could also supply and distribute them to the needy areas and the consumers for the proper growth of the economy. There were no alternatives and that is why the infrastructure sector in India has such a dominant state presence that many areas have obvious government monopolies-as in power, railways, aviation, telecommnication, etc.

Industrial Needs


India had opted for the industrial sector as its prime moving force, as we saw in the earlier pages. Now there were some areas of industries which the government had to invest in, due to several compulsive reasons. For industrialisation and its success, every economy needs the healthy presence of some 'basic industries', which are also known as the 'infrastructure industries'. 2 1 There are eight basic industries which every industrialising economy requires, namely-
(i) Iron and Steel
(ii) Cement
(iii) Coal
(iv) Crude oil
(v) Oil refining and
(vi) Electricity
(vii) Natural Gas
(viii) Fertilizer

Core industries together have a combined weight of 37.90 per cent in the Index of Industrial Production (IIP). Individual percentages of them are: Coal (weight: 4.38 per cent); Crude Oil (weight: 5.22 per cent); Natural Gas (weight:
1.71 per cent); Petroleum refinery (weight: 5.94 per cent); Fertilizer (weight: 1.25 per cent); Steel (weight: 6.68 per cent); Cement (weight: 2.41 per cent); and Electricity (weight: 10.32 per cent).]
Similar to the infrastructure sector, these basic industries also require high level of capital, technology, skilled manpower and articulation in entrepreneurship which was again considered not feasible for the private sector of the time to manage. Even if the private sector supplied goods from the 'basic industries', they might not be able to sell their products in the market due to the lower purchasing power of the consumers. Perhaps, that is why again the responsibility of developing the basic industries was taken up by the government.
Out of the six basic industries the cement sector was having some strength in the private and in iron and steel sector a lone private company was present. The coal sector was controlled by the private sector and crude oil and refining was just a beginning by them. The level of demands of an industrialising India was never to be met by the existing strength of the basic industries. Neither the required level of expansion in them was possible by the existing number of private players. With no choice left, the government decided to play the main role in them. In many of them we as a result, see a natural monopoly for the PSUs, again.

Employment Generation


The PSUs were also seen as an important part of the employment generation strategy. A government in a democratic set up cannot think only economics, but it has to realise the socio-political dimensions of the nation too. The country was faced with the serious problem of poverty and the workforce was increasing at a fast rate. Giving employment to the poor people is time-tested tool of poverty alleviation. The PSUs were thought to create enough jobs for the employable workforce of the economy.
There was also felt an immediacy for a social change in the country. The poverty of a greater section of the country was somehow connected to the age-old caste system which propitiated the stronghold of the upper castes on the ownership of land which was the only means of income and livelihood for almost above 80 per cent of the population. Along with the ambitious polic y of
land reforms, the government had decided to
provide reservations to the weaker sections of the society in government jobs. The upcoming PSUs were supposed to put such jobs at the disposal of the goverment which could have been distributed along the decided reservation policy-such reservations were considered an economic tool for social change.
In the highly capital-intensive sectors in which the government companies were going to enter, managing investible funds to set them up was not going to be an easy task. The government did manage the funds with sources like taxation, internal and external borrowing and even taking last refuge in the printing of fresh currencies. The government went to justify the high taxation and heavy public indebtness in supplying employment to the Indian employable population.
The PSUs were considered by the government as the focus of the 'trickle-down effect'. The government did everything to set up and run the PSUs as the benefits were supposed to percolate to the masses, finally reinforcing growth and development in the country. Employment in the PSUs was seen as the effort of the trickle down theory, simply said. At a point of time, Nehru even mentioned the PSUs as the 'temples of modern India'. The government went to commit even a job in every household via the PSUs-without calculating the dimensions of the future labour force in the country and the required resources to create jobs at such a high scale. But the government went on creating new PSUs without analysing the fiscal repercussions-moreover believing them to be the real engine of equitable growth. The employment generation responsibility of the PSUs was extended to such an extent by the government that most of them had over-supply of the labour force which started draining its profits on account of the salaries, wages, pensions and provident funds (the latter two had late financial impact).

Profit and Development of the Social Sector


The investment to be made by the government in PSUs was in the nature of asset creation and these entities were to be involved in production activities. It was natural for the government to gain control over the profits and dividends accruing from them. The goods and services the PSUs were to produce and sell were going to provide disposable income to the government.
The government had a conscious polic y of spending the income generated by the PSUs. They
were to be used in the supply of the 'social goods' or what is called the 'public goods'. And thus, India was to have a developed social sector. By social goods the government meant the universal supply of certain goods and services to the Indian people. These included education, healthcare, nutrition, drinking water, social security, etc., in India. It means that the PSUs were also visioned as the revenue generators for the development of

the social sector. Due to many reasons the PSUs would not be able to generate as much profit as was required for the healthy development of the social sector. This eventually hampered the availability of public goods in the country. In place of giving profits back to the government, a large number of the PSUs started incurring huge losses and required budgetary supports as a regular phenomenon.

Rise of the Private Sector


As the PSUs will take the responsibility of supplying the infrastructure and the basic industries to the economy, a base for the rise of private sector industries will be built. With the rise of the private sector industries in the country, the process of industrialisation will be completed. Out of the many roles the PSUs were supposed to play this was the most far-sighted. Whatever happened to the different roles the PSUs were assigned is a totally different matter to which we will return while discussing the industrial scenario in the country. Here we have analysed why the government in India after Independence went for such an ambitious plan of expansion of the public sector.
Besides, the PSUs were aimed at many other connected areas of developmental concerns, such as, self-sufficienc y in production, balanced regional development, spread ofsmall and ancillary industries, low and stable prices, and long-term equilibrium in balance of payment. Over time the PSUs have played a critical role in promoting the
growth and development of the country